Gregory King

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Gregory King (15 December 1648 – 29 August 1712) was an English officer of arms, engraver, cartographer and statistician.[1]

Life[edit]

Gregory King was born at Lichfield, England. His father was a surveyor and landscape gardener. Gregory was a bright boy, and his father used him as an assistant in his surveying work. At 14 Gregory became a clerk to William Dugdale, the antiquary and herald. King later (1667–69) worked for Lord Hatton, who was forming a collection of the arms of the nobility. When this project collapsed, he went to work for the dowager Lady Gerard at Sandon, Staffordshire as steward, auditor and secretary (1670–72).[2] She was the widow of Charles Gerard, 4th Baron Gerard, and remarried in 1673.[3]

In 1672 King moved to London to work as an engraver for the printer John Ogilby; he also did surveying work and engraved maps. In 1677 he was appointed Rouge Dragon Pursuivant of Arms in Ordinary in the College of Arms. He became Lancaster Herald of Arms in Ordinary in 1688 and held that post until his death in 1712. These positions in the ceremonial branch of the state were lucrative and on three occasions he was sent abroad to confer the Order of the Garter on foreign princes.

By 1695 King was started on a second official career in the business branch of the state. He was a commissioner in charge of a new tax on marriages, births and burials and later Secretary to the Commission of Public Accounts and Secretary to the Controllers of Army Accounts; in 1708 he was one of the three commissioners appointed to state the debts of the late King William.

Works[edit]

"The first great economic statistician", as Richard Stone calls him,[4] came a generation after John Graunt and William Petty and continued their work. Their work was mainly published, but King's was not: he was a confidential advisor to the government. Material from his manuscripts appeared in the writings of his friend Charles Davenant and—a century later—in Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations (Book I, Chapter VIII), and in An Estimate of the Comparative Strength of Britain by George Chalmers.[1]

King's manuscript "Natural and Political Observations and Conclusions upon the State and Condition of England", 1696, contains estimates of the population and wealth of England at the close of the 17th century. It describes the demographic characteristics of the population of England and Wales: age, gender, marital status, numbers of children, servants and "sojourners". King also calculates the amount of beer, ale, and malt consumed annually in England. These estimates are based on intelligent inferences from data available to the state as a by-product of its taxing activities. However, in more speculative mood, King considers the present and future level of world population. His Notebook contains projections of world population: around AD 5000 or 5500 the world would be "fully peopled" with 10 times the population of 1695.

"Of the Naval Trade of England, 1688, and the National Profit then Arising thereby", written in 1697, is King's statistical summary of the trade and wealth of England, 1600–1688. He calculated the increases in shipping (for war and trade), customs, coinage, buildings, fortresses, and the purchases and improvements of land.

"Gregory King's Law"[edit]

"Gregory King's Law", or the "King-Davenant law", is an estimate of by how much a deficiency in the supply of corn will raise the price of corn. It appears in Davenant's Essay upon the Probable Methods of making a People Gainers in the Balance of Trade. Since the early 19th century it has usually been attributed to King.

The relevant passage runs:

It is observed that but one-tenth the defect in the harvest may raise the price three-tenths, and when we have but half our crop of wheat, which now and then happens, the remainder is spun out by thrift and good management, and eked out by the use of other grain; but this will not do for above one year, and would be a small help in the succession of two or three unseasonable very destructive, in which many of the poorest sort perish, either for want of sufficient food or by unwholesome diet.

We take it that a defect in the harvest may raise the price of corn in the following proportions:

Defect raises the price above the common rate
1 tenth ............... 3 tenths
2 tenths ............... 8 tenths
3 tenths ............... 16 tenths
4 tenths ............... 28 tenths
5 tenths ............... 45 tenths

So that when corn rises to treble the common rate, it may be presumed that we want above one-third of the common produce; and if we should want five-tenths or half the common produce, the price would rise to near five times the common rate.[5]

In the 19th century Whewell and Jevons re-expressed the estimate as an equation. The estimate raises several questions. To whom should it be attributed, Davenant or King? How was it constructed? How accurate is it? Stone reviews the considerable literature on these questions.

Writings[edit]

  • Two Tracts by Gregory King.(a) Natural and Political Observations and Conclusions upon the State and Condition of England. (b) Of the Naval Trade of England Ao. 1688 and the National Profit then arising thereby. Edited with an introduction by George E. Barnett. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1936.

The Natural and Political Observations appear with some of King's unpublished writings in a volume edited by Peter Laslett.

  • The Earliest classics [facsimile reprints of] John Graunt, Natural and political observations made upon the bills of mortality, 1662 [and] G. King, Natural and political observations and conclusions upon the state and condition of England 1696 [from the 1804 printing] [and] 'The L.C.C. Burns Journal', a manuscript notebook containing workings for several projected works, composed c.1695-1700 with an introduction by Peter Laslett. Farnborough UK : Gregg, 1973.

References[edit]

  1. ^ a b Britannica on King
  2. ^ Hoppit 2011.
  3. ^ The National Archives, Hand, Morgan and Owen, Solicitors of Lichfield and Stafford.
  4. ^ Richard Stone, Some British Empiricists in the Social Sciences 1650-1900 (1997), p. xxii
  5. ^ The Works of Sr William D'Avenant Kt, vol. ii, pp. 224, 225, edited by Sir C. Whitworth, London (1771).

Further reading[edit]

  • Dodgson, John (2013). "Gregory King and the economic structure of early modern England: an input–output table for 1688". Economic History Review. 66 (4): 993–1016. doi:10.1111/1468-0289.12006. S2CID 153547616.
  • Hoppit, Julian (2011) [2004]. "King, Gregory (1648–1712)". Oxford Dictionary of National Biography (online ed.). Oxford University Press. doi:10.1093/ref:odnb/15563. (Subscription or UK public library membership required.)
  • Stone, Richard (1996). Some British Empiricists in the Social Sciences 1650–1900. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521571456.
  • Taylor, John A. (2005). British Empiricism and Early Political Economy: Gregory King's 1696 Estimates of National Wealth and Population. Westport, Conn.: Praeger. ISBN 9780313313066.

Resources and external links[edit]

For King's estimate of the country's population and wealth in 1688 see

Richard Stone's Nobel Prize lecture on the history of social accounting contains a brief account of King's work (including some tables)

For Gregory King's law see

The article on Davenant in the Palgrave Dictionary written at the end of the 19th century.

Whewell's discussion at the end of Lecture III

Jevons's discussion in the Section on the Variation of the Price of Corn in chapter IV